From Traditional Regional Analysis to Dynamics of Local Development: Foundations and Theoretical Reorientations

Charis Vlados, Nikolaos Deniozos, Dimos Chatzinikolaou, Agis Digkas

Abstract


The conventional and traditional regional analysis seems to gradually changing focus, content and hermeneutic optic. The regional analysis of past seems increasingly saturated, being incapable to interpret and propose policy solutions that originate primarily from the potential of local development, innovation and entrepreneurship. To this end, new, multidisciplinary approaches of local development seem to prevail progressively, leading the study of development to the analysis of dynamically evolving localities.


Full Text:

PDF

References


Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why nations fail: the origins of power, prosperity, and poverty (1. ed). New York, NY: Crown Publ.

Aghion, P., Boulanger, J., & Cohen, E. (2011). Rethinking industrial policy (Policy Briefs). Bruegel. Retrieved from https://econpapers.repec.org/paper/brepolbrf/566.htm

Aglietta, M. (1997). Régulation et crises du capitalisme (Nouv. éd. rev. et corr., augm. d’une postface inéd). Paris: Jacob.

Aglietta, M. (2000). A theory of capitalist regulation: the US experience (New ed). London: Verso.

Aglietta, M. (2010). La crise: le voies de sortie (Nouv. éd). Paris: Michalon.

Aiginger, K. (2015). Industrial Policy for a Sustainable Growth Path. In D. Bailey, K. Cowling, & P. Tomlinson (Eds.), New Perspectives on Industrial Policy for a Modern Britain (pp. 364–394). Oxford University Press.

https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198706205.003.0019

Alonso, W. (1964). Location and Land Use: Toward a General Theory of Land Rent. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.

Amin, A. (2000). Industrial districts. In A Companion in Economic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell Publisher.

Antonelli, C. (2006). The Business Governance of Localized Knowledge: An Information Economics Approach for the Economics of Knowledge. Industry and Innovation, 13(3), 227–261. https://doi.org/10.1080/13662710600858118

Araujo, M. C., Ferreira, F. H. G., Lanjouw, P., & Özler, B. (2008). Local inequality and project choice: Theory and evidence from Ecuador. Journal of Public Economics, 92(5–6), 1022–1046. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.12.005

Armstrong, H. W., & Taylor, J. (1993). Regional Economics & Policy. Harvester Wheatsheaf.

Asheim, B., & Clark, E. (2001). Creativity and Cost in Urban and Regional Development in the “New Economy.” European Planning Studies, 9(7), 805–811. https://doi.org/10.1080/09654310120079779

Asheim, B. T. (1996). Industrial districts as ‘learning regions’: A condition for prosperity. European Planning Studies, 4(4), 379–400. https://doi.org/10.1080/09654319608720354

Audretsch, D. B., & Lehmann, E. E. (2005). Does the Knowledge Spillover Theory of Entrepreneurship hold for regions? Research Policy, 34(8), 1191–1202. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2005.03.012

Aydalot, P. (Ed.). (1984). Crise et espace. Paris: Economica.

Aydalot, P. (1986). Milieux innovateurs en Europe. Paris: GREMI.

Azariadis, C., Bullard, J., & Ohanian, L. (2004). Trend-reverting fluctuations in the life-cycle model. Journal of Economic Theory, 119(2), 334–356. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0022-0531(03)00032-2

Baldwin, R. (1988). Factor Market Barriers are Trade Barriers: Gains From Trade in 1992 (Working Paper No. 2656). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w2656

Balland, P.-A., Boschma, R., & Frenken, K. (2015). Proximity and Innovation: From Statics to Dynamics. Regional Studies, 49(6), 907–920. https://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2014.883598

Becattini, G. (1975). Lo sviluppo economico della Toscana : con particolare riguardo all’industrializzazione leggera. Firenze.

Becattini, G. (2002). From Marshall’s to the Italian “Industrial Districts”. A Brief Critical Reconstruction. In A. Q. Curzio & M. Fortis (Eds.), Complexity and Industrial Clusters (pp. 83–106). Physica-Verlag HD.

Belleflamme, P., Picard, P., & Thisse, J.-F. (2000). An Economic Theory of Regional Clusters. Journal of Urban Economics, 48(1), 158–184. https://doi.org/10.1006/juec.1999.2161

Benko, G., & Lipietz, A. (Eds.). (2000). La richesse des régions: la nouvelle géographie socio-économique. Paris: Presses universitaires de France.

Best, M. H. (1990). The new competition: institutions of industrial restructuring. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.

Bhattacharya, A., Khanna, D., Schweizer, C., & Bijapurkar, A. (2017, April 25). The New Globalization: Going Beyond the Rhetoric. Retrieved September 26, 2018, from https://www.bcg.com/en-gr/publications/2017/new-globalization-going-beyond-rhetoric.aspx

Boschma, R. (2005). Proximity and Innovation: A Critical Assessment. Regional Studies, 39(1), 61–74. https://doi.org/10.1080/0034340052000320887

Boschma, R. (2015). Towards an Evolutionary Perspective on Regional Resilience. Regional Studies, 49(5), 733–751. https://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2014.959481

Boschma, R. A., & Frenken, K. (2006). Why is economic geography not an evolutionary science? Towards an evolutionary economic geography. Journal of Economic Geography, 6(3), 273–302. https://doi.org/10.1093/jeg/lbi022

Boyer, R. (2004). Théorie de la régulation. 1: Les fondamentaux. Paris: La Découverte.

Briant, A., Combes, P.-P., & Lafourcade, M. (2010). Dots to boxes: Do the size and shape of spatial units jeopardize economic geography estimations? Journal of Urban Economics, 67(3), 287–302. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2009.09.014

Brusco, S. (1982). The Emilian model: productive decentralisation and social integration. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 6(2), 167–184. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035506

Camagni, R. P. (1995). The Concept of Innovative Milieu and Its Relevance for Public Policies in European Lagging Regions. Papers in Regional Science, 74(4), 317–340. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1435-5597.1995.tb00644.x

Cameron, R. (1970). Europe’s Second Logistic. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 12(4), 452–462.

Carlino, G., & Kerr, W. R. (2014). Agglomeration and Innovation (Working Paper No. 20367). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w20367

Chinitz, B. (1966). Appropriate Goals for Regional Economic Policy. Urban Studies, 3(1), 1–7. https://doi.org/10.1080/00420986620080011

Chipman, J. S., & Winker, P. (1992). Optimal aggregation by threshold accepting: An application to the German industrial classification system (Working Paper No. 180). Diskussionsbeiträge: Serie II, Sonderforschungsbereich 178 “Internationalisierung der Wirtschaft”, Universität Konstanz. Retrieved from https://www.econstor.eu/handle/10419/101634

Chisholm, M. (1990). Regions in recession and resurgence. London: Unwin Hyman.

Clark, C. (1967). Von Thunen’s Isolated State. Oxford Economic Papers, 19(3), 370–377.

Cohen, M. D., March, J. G., & Olsen, J. P. (1972). A Garbage Can Model of Organizational Choice. Administrative Science Quarterly, 17(1), 1–25. https://doi.org/10.2307/2392088

Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1989). Innovation and Learning: The Two Faces of R & D. The Economic Journal, 99(397), 569–596. https://doi.org/10.2307/2233763

Coleman, J. S. (1988). Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital. American Journal of Sociology, 94, S95–S120.

Cooke, Phil. (2007). Social capital, embeddedness, and market interactions: An analysis of firm performance in UK regions. Review of Social Economy, 65(1), 79–106.

https://doi.org/10.1080/00346760601132170

Cooke, Philip, Gomez Uranga, M., & Etxebarria, G. (1997). Regional innovation systems: Institutional and organisational dimensions. Research Policy, 26(4–5), 475–491.

Cooke, Philip, & Wills, D. (1999). Small Firms, Social Capital and the Enhancement of Business Performance Through Innovation Programmes. Small Business Economics, 13(3), 219–234. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1008178808631

Courlet, C. (2008). L’économie territoriale. Saint-Martin-d’Hères (Isère): Pug.

Cox, K. R. (1998). Spaces of dependence, spaces of engagement and the politics of scale, or: looking for local politics. Political Geography, 17(1), 1–23. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0962-6298(97)00048-6

Crespo, J., Suire, R., & Vicente, J. (2014). Lock-in or lock-out? How structural properties of knowledge networks affect regional resilience. Journal of Economic Geography, 14(1), 199–219. https://doi.org/10.1093/jeg/lbt006

Cumming, G., Cumming, D. H. M., & Redman, C. (2006). Scale Mismatches in Social-Ecological Systems: Causes, Consequences, and Solutions. Ecology and Society, 11(1). https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-01569-110114

Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. (1963). A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. New Jersey: Prentice Hall.

Dakhli, M., & De Clercq, D. (2004). Human capital, social capital, and innovation: a multi-country study. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development, 16(2), 107–128.

David, P. (1985). Clio and the Economics of QWERTY. American Economic Review, 75(2), 332–337.

Davis, D. R., & Weinstein, D. E. (1996). Does Economic Geography Matter for International Specialization? (Working Paper No. 5706). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w5706

Deardorff, A. V. (1995). Determinants of Bilateral Trade: Does Gravity Work in a Neoclassical World? (NBER Working Papers No. 5377). National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/p/nbr/nberwo/5377.html

Deardorff, A. V. (2004). Trade and location: A moving example motivated by Japan (Hi-Stat Discussion Paper Series No. d04-56). Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University. Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/p/hst/hstdps/d04-56.html

Deardorff, A. V. (2005). Ricardian comparative advantage with intermediate inputs. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 16(1), 11–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2004.11.003

Debaere, P. (1998). “Endowments Do Matter” Relative Factor Abundance and Trade (Working Papers No. 429). Research Seminar in International Economics, University of Michigan. Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/p/mie/wpaper/429.html

Dosi, G. (2016). Beyond the ‘magic of the market’. The slow return of industrial policy (but not yet in Italy). Economia e Politica Industriale, 43(3), 261–264. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40812-016-0041-x

Dunn, E. S. (1954). The location of agricultural production. Gainesville, Fla.: University of Florida Press. Retrieved from https://trove.nla.gov.au/version/23950100

Faggian, A., & McCann, P. (2009). Human capital, graduate migration and innovation in British regions. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 33(2), 317–333.

Filho, N. M., & Scorzafave, L. (2001). Employment and Inequality Outcomes in Brazil (p. 36). OECD.

Fingleton, B. (2001). Theoretical economic geography and spatial econometrics: dynamic perspectives. Journal of Economic Geography, 1(2), 201–225. https://doi.org/10.1093/jeg/1.2.201

Fingleton, B., & López‐Bazo, E. (2006). Empirical growth models with spatial effects*. Papers in Regional Science, 85(2), 177–198. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1435-5957.2006.00074.x

Florida, R. (1996a). Lean and Green: The Move to Environmentally Conscious Manufacturing. California Management Review, 39(1), 80–105. https://doi.org/10.2307/41165877

Florida, R. (1996b). Regional Creative Destruction: Production Organization, Globalization, and the Economic Transformation of the Midwest. Economic Geography, 72(3), 314–334. https://doi.org/10.2307/144403

Frank, André Gunder. (1967). Capitalism and underdevelopment in Latin America: historical studies of Chile and Brazil. New Tork: Monthly Review Press.

Frank, Andre Gunder. (1976). Economic Genocide in Chile: Open Letter to Milton Friedman and Arnold Harberger. Economic and Political Weekly, 11(24), 880–888.

Friedman, D. (1998a). Evolutionary economics goes mainstream: A review of the theory of learning in games. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 8(4), 423–432. https://doi.org/10.1007/s001910050071

Friedman, D. (1998b). On economic applications of evolutionary game theory. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 8(1), 15–43. https://doi.org/10.1007/s001910050054

Fujita, M., & Krugman, P. (1995). When is the economy monocentric?: von Thünen and Chamberlin unified. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 25(4), 505–528. https://doi.org/10.1016/0166-0462(95)02098-F

Fujita, M., Krugman, P. R., & Venables, A. (1999). The spatial economy: cities, regions and international trade. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press.

Galbraith, J. K. (2007). The New Industrial State (1st Princeton Ed edition (first published in 1967)). Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press.

Gilpin, R., & Gilpin, J. M. (2001). Global political economy: understanding the international economic order. Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press.

Gordon, I. R., & McCann, P. (2000). Industrial Clusters: Complexes, Agglomeration and/or Social Networks? Urban Studies, 37(3), 513–532. https://doi.org/10.1080/0042098002096

Guillén, M. F. (2001). The Limits of Convergence: Globalization and Organizational Change in Argentina, South Korea, and Spain. Princeton University Press. Retrieved from https://www.jstor.org/stable/j.ctt7scd0

Hadjimichalis, C. (2011). Uneven geographical development and socio-spatial justice and solidarity: European regions after the 2009 financial crisis. European Urban and Regional Studies, 18(3), 254–274. https://doi.org/10.1177/0969776411404873

Hadjimichalis, C., & Hudson, R. (2006). Networks, Regional Development and Democratic Control. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 30(4), 858–872. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-2427.2006.00687.x

Hadjimichalis, C., & Hudson, R. (2014). Contemporary Crisis Across Europe and the Crisis of Regional Development Theories. Regional Studies, 48(1), 208–218. https://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2013.834044

Hall, B. H. (2004). Innovation and Diffusion (Working Paper No. 10212). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w10212

Hannon, B. (1997). The use of analogy in biology and economics: From biology to economics, and back. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 8(4), 471–488. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0954-349X(97)00019-2

Harle, V., Moisio, S., & Aalto, P. (2016). Global and Regional Problems: Towards an Interdisciplinary Study. London: Taylor & Francis. Retrieved from http://public.eblib.com/choice/publicfullrecord.aspx?p=4512760

Harvey, D. (2006). The limits to capital (New and fully updated edition). London ; New York: Verso.

Healey, M., & Ilbery, B. W. (1990). Location and change : perspectives on economic geography. Oxford ; New York : Oxford University Press. Retrieved from https://trove.nla.gov.au/version/6537441

Henderson, J. V., & Thisse, J.-F. (Eds.). (2008). Cities and geography (1. ed., Repr). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

Hodgson, G. M. (1999). Economics and evolution: bringing life back into economics. Ann Arbor (Mich.): University of Michigan Press.

Holland, S. (1976). Capital versus the regions. London: Macmillan.

Iansiti, M., & Levien, R. (2004). The keystone advantage: what the new dynamics of business ecosystems mean for strategy, innovation, and sustainability. Boston, Mass: Harvard Business School Press.

Jacobs, J. (1961). The Death and Life of Great American Cities. New York: Random House.

Kaldor, N. (1970). The Case for Regional Policies*. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 17(3), 337–348. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9485.1970.tb00712.x

Kaldor, N., Targetti, F., & Thirlwall, A. P. (1989). Further essays on economic theory and policy. London : Duckworth. Retrieved from https://trove.nla.gov.au/work/16590851

Kaufmann, A., & Tödtling, F. (2001). Science-industry interaction in the process of innovation: the importance of boundary-crossing between systems. Research Policy, 30(5), 791–804.

Knox, P., Agnew, J., & McCarthy, L. (2008). The Geography of the World Economy (5th ed). London : Hodder Education. Retrieved from https://trove.nla.gov.au/work/17947744

Kondratieff, N. D., & Stolper, W. F. (1935). The Long Waves in Economic Life. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 17(6), 105–115. https://doi.org/10.2307/1928486

Kotz, D. M. (2003). Neoliberalism and the Social Structure of Accumulation Theory of Long-Run Capital Accumulation. Review of Radical Political Economics, 35(3), 263–270. https://doi.org/10.1177/0486613403255542

Krugman, P. (1980). Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and the Pattern of Trade. The American Economic Review, 70(5), 950–959.

Krugman, P. (1991). Increasing Returns and Economic Geography. Journal of Political Economy, 99(3), 483–499. https://doi.org/10.1086/261763

Krugman, P. R. (1985). Increasing Returns and the Theory of International Trade (Working Paper No. 1752). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w1752

Krugman, P. R., Obstfeld, M., & Melitz, M. J. (2018). International economics: theory & policy (Eleventh Edition). New York: Pearson.

Kuhn, T. S. (1963). The Function of Dogma in Scientific Research. In Scientific Change (Symposium on the History of Science, University of Oxford, 9–15 July 1961) (pp. 347–369). New York ; London: Basic Books and Heineman.

Kuhn, T. S. (1977). The essential tension: selected studies in scientific tradition and change. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Kuhn, T. S. (1996). The structure of scientific revolutions (3rd ed (Originally published: 1962)). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

Kuznets, S. (1973). Modern Economic Growth: Findings and Reflections. The American Economic Review, 63(3), 247–258.

Kuznets, S. (1980). Driving forces of economic growth: What can we learn from history ? Review of World Economics, 116(3), 409–431. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02708815

Laudicina, P. A., & Peterson, E. R. (2016). From Globalization to Islandization (Global Business Policy Council (GBPC) /Research Report) (p. 26). ATKearney. Retrieved from https://www.atkearney.com/web/global-business-policy-council/article?/a/from-globalization-to-islandization

Launhardt, W. (1882). Die Bestimmung des zweckmässigsten Standortes einer gewerblichen Anlage. Zeitschrift Des Vereines Deutscher Ingenieure, 26, 106–115.

Laursen, K., & Meliciani, V. (2000). The Importance of Technology-Based Intersectoral Linkages for Market Share Dynamics. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 136(4), 702–723.

Lazzeretti, L., Sedita, S. R., & Caloffi, A. (2014). Founders and disseminators of cluster research. Journal of Economic Geography, 14(1), 21–43. https://doi.org/10.1093/jeg/lbs053

Lee, E., & Vivarelli, M. (2006). The social impact of globalization in the developing countries. International Labour Review, 145(3), 167–184. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1564-913X.2006.tb00016.x

Lewin, R. (2000). Complexity: Life at the Edge of Chaos (2nd edition). Chicago, Ill: University of Chicago Press.

Lipietz, A. (1986). New Tendencies in the International Division of Labour: Regimes of Accumulation and Modes of Regulation. In Production, Work, and Territory: The Geographical Anatomy of Industrial Capitalism (pp. 16–40). Boston: Allen and Unwin.

Lösch, A. (1954). Economics of location. New Haven,: Yale University Press (Originally published in 1939). Retrieved from http://archive.org/details/economicsoflocat00ls

Malecki, E. J. (1983). Technology and Regional Development: A Survey. International Regional Science Review, 8(2), 89–125. https://doi.org/10.1177/016001768300800201

Markusen, A. R. (1985). Profit cycles, oligopoly, and regional development. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press.

Marshall, A. (1879). The Pure Theory of (Domestic) Values (History of Economic Thought Books). McMaster University Archive for the History of Economic Thought. Retrieved from https://econpapers.repec.org/bookchap/hayhetboo/marshall1879a.htm

Marshall, A. (1919). Industry and Trade: A Study of Industrial Technique and Business Organization and of Their Influences on the Condition of Various Classes and Nations. London ; New York: MacMillian and Co. Limited.

Marshall, A. (1920). Principles of Economics (8th Edition). London: Macmillan.

Martin, R. (2008). Institutional Approaches in Economic Geography. In A Companion to Economic Geography (pp. 77–94). Wiley-Blackwell. https://doi.org/10.1002/9780470693445.ch6

Martin, R. (2009). Roepke Lecture in Economic Geography-Rethinking Regional Path Dependence: Beyond Lock-in to Evolution: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY. Economic Geography, 86(1), 1–27. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1944-8287.2009.01056.x

Maskell, P., & Malmberg, A. (1999). Localised Learning and Industrial Competitiveness. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 23(2), 167–185.

Maurseth, P. B. (2003). Economic Convergence through Savings, Trade and Technology Flows: Lessons from Recent Research. Forum for Development Studies, 30(1), 29–58. https://doi.org/10.1080/08039410.2003.9666229

McCann, P., & Ortega-Argilés, R. (2013). Modern regional innovation policy. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society, 6(2), 187–216. https://doi.org/10.1093/cjres/rst007

Mcdonough, T. (1995). Lenin, Imperialism, and the Stages of Capitalist Development. Science & Society, 59(3), 339–367.

McDonough, T. (2007). The Marxian Theory of Capitalist Stages. In Transitions in Latin America and in Poland and Syria (Vol. 24, pp. 241–280). Emerald Group Publishing Limited. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0161-7230(07)24007-6

Metcalfe, J. S., & Soete, L. (1984). Notes on the evolution of technology and international competition. In Science and Technology Policy in the 1980’s and Beyond. London: Longman.

Moore, J. (1993). Predators and prey: a new ecology of competition. Harvard Business Review, 71(3), 75–86.

Morgan, K. (1997). The Learning Region: Institutions, Innovation and Regional Renewal. Regional Studies, 31(5), 491–503. https://doi.org/10.1080/00343409750132289

Muller, E. (2001). Knowledge, Innovation Processes and Regions. In K. Koschatzky, M. Kulicke, & A. Zenker (Eds.), Innovation Networks (pp. 37–51). Physica-Verlag HD.

Newman, B. J., Johnston, C. D., & Lown, P. L. (2015). False Consciousness or Class Awareness? Local Income Inequality, Personal Economic Position, and Belief in American Meritocracy. American Journal of Political Science, 59(2), 326–340. https://doi.org/10.1111/ajps.12153

Nonaka, I., & Takeuchi, H. (1995). The knowledge-creating company: how Japanese companies create the dynamics of innovation. New York: Oxford University Press.

North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge ; New York: Cambridge University Press.

OECD. (2009). Investing for Growth: Building Innovative Regions (Conclusions of the meeting of the territorial development policy committee (TDPC) at ministerial level). Paris. Retrieved from http://www.oecd.org/cfe/regional-policy/TDPC%202009%20Ministerial%20Conclusions.pdf

Ohlin, B. G. (1933). Interregional and international trade, by Bertil Ohlin. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Olson, M. (2003). The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of groups (21. printing (Publication: January 1971)). Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Univ. Press.

Palander, T. (1935). Beitrage Zur Standurts theories. In Industrial Location (pp. 75–93). New York: John Wiley (1981).

Peneder, M. (2016). Competitiveness and industrial policy: from rationalities of failure towards the ability to evolve. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 829–858. https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/bew025

Perrons, D. C. (1981). The role of Ireland in the new international division of labour: A proposed framework for regional analysis. Regional Studies, 15(2), 81–100. https://doi.org/10.1080/09595238100185111

Pfaffermayr, M. (2007). Conditional Beta- and Sigma-Convergence in Space: A Maximum-Likelihood Approach (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID 1013297). Rochester, NY: Social Science Research Network. Retrieved from https://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=1013297

Pike, A., Rodríguez-Pose, A., & Tomaney, J. (2006). Local and regional development. London : New York: Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group.

Pike, A., Rodríguez-Pose, A., & Tomaney, J. (2007). What Kind of Local and Regional Development and for Whom? Regional Studies, 41(9), 1253–1269. https://doi.org/10.1080/00343400701543355

Polanyi, K. (2001). The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time (2 edition (first UK edition 1945)). Boston, MA: Beacon Press.

Porter, M. (1990). The competitive advantage of nations. New York: Free Press.

Porter, M. (2000). Location, Competition, and Economic Development: Local Clusters in a Global Economy. Economic Development Quarterly, 14(1), 15–34. https://doi.org/10.1177/089124240001400105

Portes, A. (1998). Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology. Annual Review of Sociology, 24(1), 1–24. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.24.1.1

Posner, M. V. (1961). International Trade and Technical Change. Oxford Economic Papers, 13(3), 323–341.

Putnam, R. (1993). The Prosperous Community: Social Capital and Public Life. The American Prospect, (13), 35–42.

Reuveny, R., & Thompson, W. R. (2001). Leading Sectors, Lead Economies, and Economic Growth. Review of International Political Economy, 8(4), 689–719.

Ricardo, D. (1817). On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. London: J. Murray.

Rinkinen, S., & Harmaakorpi, V. (2018). The business ecosystem concept in innovation policy context: building a conceptual framework. Innovation: The European Journal of Social Science Research, 31(3), 333–349. https://doi.org/10.1080/13511610.2017.1300089

Rivera-Batiz, L. A., & Romer, P. M. (1991). International Trade with Endogenous Technological Change (Working Paper No. 3594). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w3594

Rodrik, D. (2011). The globalization paradox: why global markets, states, and democracy can’t coexist. Oxford ; New York: Oxford University Press.

Rostow, W. W. (1952). The process of economic growth. New York: Norton. Retrieved from http://catalog.hathitrust.org/api/volumes/oclc/2691612.html

Rostow, W. W. (1956). The Take-Off Into Self-Sustained Growth. The Economic Journal, 66(261), 25–48. https://doi.org/10.2307/2227401

Rostow, W. W. (1959). The Stages of Economic Growth. The Economic History Review, 12(1), 1–16. https://doi.org/10.2307/2591077

Rostow, W. W. (1960). The stages of economic growth: A non-communist manifesto. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Rostow, W. W. (1963). Leading Sectors and the Take-off. In W. W. Rostow (Ed.), The Economics of Take-Off into Sustained Growth (pp. 1–21). London: Palgrave Macmillan UK. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-63959-5_1

Rothschild, M. (1990). Bionomics: the inevitability of capitalism (1st ed). New York: H. Holt.

Samuelson, P. A. (1948). International Trade and the Equalisation of Factor Prices. The Economic Journal, 58(230), 163–184. https://doi.org/10.2307/2225933

Samuelson, P. A. (1949). International Factor-Price Equalisation Once Again. The Economic Journal, 59(234), 181–197. https://doi.org/10.2307/2226683

Santos, M. (1977). Spatial Dialectics: The Two Circuits of Urban Economy in Underdeveloped Countries. Antipode, 9(3), 49–60. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8330.1977.tb00092.x

Sapir, J. (2011). La démondialisation. Paris: Seuil.

Saxenian, A. (1990). Regional Networks and the Resurgence of Silicon Valley. California Management Review, 33(1), 89–112. https://doi.org/10.2307/41166640

Saxenian, A. (1994). Regional advantage: culture and competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.

Sayer, R. A. (1992). Method in social science: a realist approach (2nd ed). London ; New York: Routledge.

Schumpeter, J. (1934). The theory of economic development; an inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycle. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.

Schumpeter, J. (1939). Business cycles: a theoretical, historical, and statistical analysis of the capitalist process. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Scott, A. (1988). New industrial spaces: Flexible production organization and regional development in North America and Western Europe. London: Pion.

Simon, H. A. (1947). Administrative Behavior: a Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organization. New York: Macmillan.

Simon, H. A. (1955). A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69(1), 99–118. https://doi.org/10.2307/1884852

Simon, H. A. (1973). Applying Information Technology to Organization Design. Public Administration Review, 33(3), 268–278. https://doi.org/10.2307/974804

Simon, H. A. (1996). The sciences of the artificial (Third Edition). Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. Retrieved from http://ieeexplore.ieee.org/servlet/opac?bknumber=6267338

Skinner, A. (1988). Adam Smith and economic liberalism. Edinburgh: David Hume Institute.

Smith, A. (1776). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. London: Strahan and Cadell.

Storper, M. (1991). Industrialization, economic development and the regional question in the Third World: from import substitution to flexible production. London: Pion.

Storper, M., & Christopherson, S. (1987). Flexible Specialization and Regional Industrial Agglomerations: The Case of the U.S. Motion Picture Industry. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 77(1), 104–117. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8306.1987.tb00148.x

Thirlwall, A. P. (2006). Growth and development: with special reference to developing economies (8th ed). Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire ; New York, N.Y. : Palgrave Macmillan. Retrieved from https://trove.nla.gov.au/work/2169545

Thünen, V. (1826). Der Isolierte Staat in Beziehung auf Landwirtschaf und Nationalokonomie.

Tomaskovic-Devey, D., & Roscigno, V. J. (1997). Uneven Development and Local Inequality in the U.S. South: The Role of Outside Investment, Landed Elites, and Racial Dynamics. Sociological Forum, 12(4), 565–597. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1022174707289

Townroe, P. M. (1983). United Kingdom. In Industrial mobility and migration in the European Community. Aldershot: Gower.

Veblen, T. (1898). Why is Economics not an Evolutionary Science? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 12(4), 373–397. https://doi.org/10.2307/1882952

Verdoorn, P. J. (1980). Verdoorn’s Law in Retrospect: A Comment. The Economic Journal, 90(358), 382–385. https://doi.org/10.2307/2231798

Vines, D. (1987). Macroeconomic policy after monetarism: a summary. Royal Bank of Scotland Quarterly Review ; 1986.

Vivarelli, M. (2004). Globalization, Skills and Within-Country Income Inequality in Developing Countries. In Understanding Globalization, Employment and Poverty Reduction (pp. 211–243). New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

Vlados, C. (2004). La dynamique du triangle stratégie, technologie et management : l’insertion des entreprises grecques dans la globalisation. Paris 10. Retrieved from http://www.theses.fr/2004PA100022

Vlados, C. (2005). The insertion of Greek firms into globalization: The dynamics of the triangle of strategy, technology and management. Presented at the Managing Global Trends and Challenges in a Turbulent Economy, University of the Aegean, Department of Business Administration.

Vlados, C. (2012). The search of competitiveness and the entrepreneurial evolution in a global environment: Toward a new approach of development dynamics based on the case of Greek productive system. Journal of Management Sciences and Regional Development, (8), 91–116.

Vlados, C., Deniozos, N., & Chatzinikolaou, D. (2018a). Global Crisis, Innovation and Change Management: Towards a New Systemic Perception of the Current Globalization Restructuring. International Business Research, 11(8), 9–29. https://doi.org/10.5539/ibr.v11n8p9

Vlados, C., Deniozos, N., & Chatzinikolaou, D. (2018b). The “evil globalization” & the central dialectic tug-of-war in the new globalization’s shaping. Civitas Gentium, 6(1), 89–134.

Vlados, C., Deniozos, N., Chatzinikolaou, D., & Demertzis, M. (2018a). Perceiving Competitiveness under the Restructuring Process of Globalization. International Journal of Business and Management, 13(8), 135–153. https://doi.org/10.5539/ijbm.v13n8p135

Vlados, C., Deniozos, N., Chatzinikolaou, D., & Demertzis, M. (2018b). Towards an Evolutionary Understanding of the Current Global Socio-economic Crisis and Restructuring: From a Conjunctural to a Structural and Evolutionary Perspective. Research in World Economy, 9(1), 15–33. https://doi.org/10.5430/rwe.v9n1p15

Weber, A. (1909). Uber den Standort der Industrien.

Weber, A. (1929). The Theory of the Location of Industries. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Weick, K. E. (1993). The Collapse of Sensemaking in Organizations: The Mann Gulch Disaster. Administrative Science Quarterly, 38(4), 628–652. https://doi.org/10.2307/2393339

Williamson, O. E. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. Free Press.

Wingo, L. (1961). An Economic Model of the Utilization of Urban Land. Papers in Regional Science, 7(1), 191–205. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1435-5597.1961.tb01779.x

Witt, U. (2008). What is specific about evolutionary economics? Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 18(5), 547–575. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-008-0107-7

World Commission on Environment and Development (Ed.). (1987). Our common future. Oxford ; New York: Oxford University Press.

Καλογερέσης, Θ., Θάνης, Η., & Λαμπριανίδης, Λ. (2016). Θεωρίες Περιφερειακής Ανάπτυξης. In Χωρική ανάπτυξη και ανθρώπινο δυναμικό: Νέες θεωρητικές προσεγγίσεις και η εφαρμογή τους στην Ελλάδα. Αθήνα: Εκδόσεις Κριτική.

Κόνσολας, Ν. (1997). Σύγχρονη περιφεpειακή οικονομική πολιτική. Αθήνα: Παπαζήσης.




DOI: https://doi.org/10.5296/ijrd.v6i1.14230

Refbacks

  • There are currently no refbacks.


Copyright (c) 2019 Charis Vlados, Nikolaos Deniozos, Dimos Chatzinikolaou, Agis Digkas

Creative Commons License
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.

Interantional Journal of Regional Development  ISSN 2373-9851 Email: ijrd@macrothink.org

Copyright © Macrothink Institute 

To make sure that you can receive messages from us, please add the 'macrothink.org' domains to your e-mail 'safe list'. If you do not receive e-mail in your 'inbox', please check your 'spam' or 'junk' folder.